F.A. Hayek's seminal paper, Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle, is a must-read for anyone keen on a deeper understanding of the Austrian Business Cycle Theory (ABCT). Together with Hayek's other seminal paper on this subject, Prices and Production (these two papers were highly influential in securing Hayek the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1974), and Ludwig von Mises's papers and chapters (refer to his book Human Action), these writings are a natural starting point for understanding the theory. Studying the writings of these two masters of Austrian Economics and the ABCT also serve as a safeguard against being mislead by less thorough explanations of the theory. Links to theses papers and chapters can be found at the bottom of this post. In general, Mises.org is by far the best online resource for Austrian Economics.
Below is a selection of some of the most crucial paragraphs from Hayek's Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle in my opinion. The below headings correspond to those in the original paper. Although skimming through this selection is no substitute for reading the full paper, hopefully it will fuel your interest to read more on the subject.
Some Key Points from
F.A. Hayek's Monetary
Theory and the Trade Cycle (published in June 1932)
Preface
·
In particular, my Prices and
Production, originally published in England, should be considered as an
essential complement to the present publication.
While I have here emphasized the monetary causes which start the
cyclical fluctuations, I have, in that later publication, concentrated
on the successive changes in the real structure of production, which constitute
those fluctuations. This essential complement of my theory seems to me to
be the more important since, in consequence of actual economic
developments, the over-simplified monetary explanations have gained
undeserved prominence in recent times.
·
It is a curious fact that the
general disinclination to explain the past boom by monetary factors has been
quickly replaced by an even greater readiness to hold the present working of
our monetary organization exclusively responsible for our present plight. And
the same stabilizers who believed that nothing was wrong with the boom and that
it might last indefinitely because prices did not rise, now believe that
everything could be set right again if only we would use the weapons of
monetary policy to prevent prices from falling. The same superficial view which
sees no other harmful effect of a credit expansion but the rise of the price
level, now believes that our only difficulty is a fall in the price level,
caused by credit contraction.
There can, of course, be little doubt that, at the present time, a
deflationary process is going on and that an indefinite continuation of that
deflation would do inestimable harm. But this does not, by any means,
necessarily mean that the deflation is the original cause of our difficulties
or that we could overcome these difficulties by compensating for the
deflationary tendencies, at present operative in our economic system, by
forcing more money into circulation. There is no reason to assume that the
crisis was started by a deliberate deflationary action on the part of the
monetary authorities, or that the deflation itself is anything but a secondary
phenomenon a process induced by the maladjustments of industry left over from
the boom. If, however, the deflation is not a cause but an effect of the unprofitableness
of industry, then it is surely vain to hope that, by reversing the deflationary
process, we can regain lasting prosperity. Far from following a deflationary
policy, Central Banks, particularly in the United States, have been making
earlier and more far-reaching efforts than have ever been undertaken before to
combat the depression by a policy of credit expansion — with the result that
the depression has lasted longer and has become more severe than any preceding
one. What we need is a readjustment of those elements in the structure of
production and of prices which existed before the deflation began and which
then made it unprofitable for industry to borrow. But, instead of furthering
the inevitable liquidation of the maladjustments brought about by the boom during
the last three years, all conceivable means have been used to prevent that
readjustment from taking place; and one of these means, which has been
repeatedly tried though without success, from the earliest to the most recent
stages of depression, has been this deliberate policy of credit expansion.
It is
very probable that the much discussed rigidities, which had already grown up in
many parts of the modern economic system before 1929,
would, in any case, have made the process of readjustment much slower and more
painful. It is also probable that these very resistances to readjustment would
have set up a severe deflationary process which would finally have overcome
those rigidities. To what extent, under the given situation of a relatively
rigid price and wage system, this deflationary process is perhaps not only
inevitable but is even the quickest way of bringing about the required result,
is a very difficult question, about which, on the basis of our present
knowledge, I should be afraid to make any definite pronouncement.
It seems
certain, however, that we shall merely make matters worse if we aim at curing
the deflationary symptoms and, at the same time (by the erection of trade
barriers and other forms of state intervention) do our best to increase rather
than to decrease the fundamental maladjustments. More than that: while the
advantages of such a course are, to say the least, uncertain, the new dangers
which it creates are great. To combat the depression by a forced credit
expansion is to attempt to cure the evil by the very means which brought it
about; because we are suffering from a misdirection of production, we want to
create further misdirection — a procedure which can only lead to a much more severe crisis as soon as
the credit expansion comes to an
end.
·
But whatever may be our hope for the
future, the one thing of which we must be painfully aware at the present time
—a fact which no writer on these problems should fail to impress upon his
readers — is how little we really know of the forces which we are trying to
influence by deliberate management; so little indeed that it must remain an
open question whether we would try if we knew more.
The Problem of the Trade Cycle
·
Trade cycle theory itself is only expected to explain
how certain prices are determined, and to state their influence on production
and consumption; and the determining conditions of these phenomena are already
given by elementary theory.
·
There is a fundamental difficulty
inherent in all Trade Cycle theories which take as their starting point an
empirically ascertained disturbance of the equilibrium of the various branches
of production. This difficulty arises because, in stating the effects of that
disturbance, they have to make use of the logic of equilibrium theory. Yet this
logic, properly followed through, can do no more than demonstrate that such
disturbances of equilibrium can come only from outside — i.e. that they
represent a change in the economic data — and that the economic system always
reacts to such changes by its well-known methods of adaptation, i.e. by the
formation of a new equilibrium. No tendency towards the special expansion of
certain branches of production, however plausibly adduced, no chance shift in
demand, in distribution or in productivity, could adequately explain, within
the framework of this theoretical system, why a general 'disproportionality'
between supply and demand should arise. For the essential means of explanation
in static theory, which is, at the same time, the indispensable assumption for the
explanation of particular price variations, is the assumption that prices
supply an automatic mechanism for equilibrating supply and demand.
The next
section will deal with these difficulties in more detail: a mere hint should
therefore be sufficient at this point. At the moment we have only to draw
attention to the fact that the problem before us cannot be solved by examining
the effect of a certain cause within the framework, and by the methods, of equilibrium theory. Any
theory which limits itself to
the explanation of empirically observed interconnections by the methods of elementary
theory necessarily contains a self-contradiction.
·
Money
being a commodity which, unlike all others, is incapable of finally satisfying
demand, its introduction does away with the rigid interdependence and
self-sufficiency of the 'closed system of equilibrium, and makes possible
movements which would be excluded from the latter. Here we have a
starting-point which fulfils the essential conditions for any satisfactory
theory of the Trade Cycle. It shows, in a purely deductive way, the possibility
and the necessity of movements which do not at any given moment tend
towards a situation which, in the absence of changes in the economic 'data',
could continue indefinitely. It shows that, on the contrary, these movements
lead to such a 'disproportionality' between certain parts of the system that
the given situation cannot continue.
But while it seems that it was a sound instinct which
led economists to begin by looking on the monetary side for an explanation of
cyclical fluctuations, it also seems probable that the one-sided development of
the theory of money has, as yet, prevented any satisfactory solution to the
problem being found. Monetary theories of the Trade Cycle succeeded in giving
prominence to the right questions and, in many cases, made important contributions
towards their solution; but the reason why an unassailable solution has not yet
been put forward seems to reside in the fact that all the adherents of the
monetary theory of the Trade Cycle have sought an explanation either
exclusively or predominantly in the superficial phenomena of changes in the
value of money, while failing to pursue the far more profound and fundamental
effects of the process by which money is introduced into the economic system,
as distinct from its effect on prices in general. Nor did they follow up the consequences
of the fundamental diversity between a money economy and the pure barter
economy which is assumed in static theory.
·
It will be shown, in particular,
that the Wicksell-Mises theory of the effects of a divergence between the
'natural' and the money rate of interest already contains the most important
elements of an explanation, and has only to be freed from any direct reference
to a purely imaginary 'general money
value* (as has already been partly done by Prof. Mises) in order to form the
basis of a Trade Cycle theory sufficing for a deductive explanation of all the
elements in the Trade Cycle.
Non-Monetary
Theories of the Trade Cycle
·
As has already been indicated in the
first chapter, none of them [the non-monetary theories] is able to overcome the
contradiction between the course of economic events as described by them and the
fundamental ideas of the theoretical system which they have to utilize in order
to explain that course.
·
The task is made rather easier by
the fact that there does exist to-day, on at least one point, a far-reaching
agreement among the different theories. They all regard the emergence of a disproportionality
among the various productive groups, and in particular the excessive
production of capital goods, as the first and main thing to be explained.
·
The phenomena of the upward trend of
the cycle and of the culminating boom
constitute a problem only because they inevitably bring about a slump in sales — i.e. a falling-off of economic activity —
which is not occasioned by any corresponding change in the original
economic data.
·
The
prevailing disproportionality theories are in agreement in one respect. They all see the cause of the
slump in the fact that, during the boom, for various reasons, the productive
apparatus is expanded more than is warranted by the corresponding flow of
consumption; there finally appears a scarcity of finished consumption goods,
thus causing a rise in the price of production goods (which amounts to the same
thing as a rise in the rate of interest) so that it becomes unprofitable to
employ the enlarged productive apparatus or, in many cases, to complete it.
·
In the first place there is nothing
to be gained from an examination of those theories which seek to explain
cyclical fluctuations by corresponding cyclical changes in certain external
circumstances, while merely using the unquestionable methods of equilibrium
theory to explain the economic
phenomena which follow from these changes. To decide on the correctness of
these theories is beyond the competence of Economics. In the second place, it
is best, for the moment, to exclude from consideration those theories whose
argument depends so entirely on the assumption of monetary changes that when
the latter are excluded no systematic explanation is left.
·
It is not,
therefore, the simple fact of fluctuation in the production of capital goods
(which is certainly inevitable in the course of economic growth) which has to
be explained.
The real problem is the growth of excessive
fluctuations in the capital goods industries out of the inevitable and
irregular fluctuations of the rest of the economic system, and the disproportional
development, arising from these, of the two main branches of production.
·
The
simplest way of deductively explaining excessive fluctuations in the production
of capital goods is by reference to the long period of time which is
necessary, under modern conditions, for preparing the fixed capital goods which
enable the expansion of the productive process to take place.
·
But none
of them get over the real difficulty — namely: Why do the forces tending to
restore equilibrium become temporarily ineffective and why do they only come
into action again when it is too late?
·
Production is generally guided not by any knowledge of
the actual size of the total demand, but by the price to be obtained in the
market.
·
It is however, the task of Trade Cycle theory to show
under what conditions a break may occur in that tendency towards equilibrium
which is described in pure analysis – i.e. why prices, in contradiction to the
conclusions of static theory, do not bring about such changes in the quantities
produced as would correspond to an equilibrium situation.
·
We may attempt this task by asking
what kind of reactions will be brought about by the original change in the
economic data, which is supposed to cause the excessive extension of the
production of capital goods, and how, in such cases, a new equilibrium can
result. Whether the original impetus comes from the demand side or the supply
side, the assumption from which we have to start is always a price —or rather
an expected price — which renders it profitable, under the new conditions, to
extend production.
·
…every attempt to extend the productive apparatus must
necessarily bring about, besides the rise in factor prices, a further checking
force – viz. a rise in the rate of interest. This greatly strengthens the
effect of the rise in factor prices. It makes a greater margin between
factor-prices and product-prices necessary just when this margin threatens to
diminish. The maintenance of equilibrium is thus further secured.
…all contemporary theories agree in regarding
the function of interest as one of equalising the supply of capital and the
demand arising in various branches of production. Until some special reason can be adduced why it should not fulfil this
function in any given case, we have to assume, in accordance with the fundamental thesis of static
theory, that it always keeps the supply of capital goods in equilibrium with
that of consumption goods. This assumption is just as indispensable, and just
as inevitable, as a starting-point, as the main assumption that the supply of
and demand for any kind of goods will be equilibrated by movements in the
prices of those goods.
·
Only when we come to consider the second group of
prices (those paid for borrowed capital or, in other words, interest) is it
conceivable that disturbances might creep in, since, in this case, price
formation does not act directly, by equalising demand for and supply of capital
goods, but indirectly, through its effect on money capital, whose supply need
not correspond to that of real capital [the first group is prices of goods and
services used for productive purposes]
·
Assuming that the rate of interest always determines
the point to which the available volume of savings enables productive plant to
be extended – and is it only by this assumption that we can explain what
determines the rate of interest at all – any allegations of a discrepancy
between savings and investments must be backed up by a demonstration why, in
the given case, interest does not fulfil this function.
·
At one point or another, all theories which start to
explain cyclical fluctuations by miscalculations or ignorance as regards the
economic situation fall into the same error as those naïve explanations which
base themselves on the “planlessness” of the economic system. They overlook the
fact that, in the exchange economy, production is governed by prices,
independently of any knowledge of the whole process on the part of individual
producers, so that it is only when the pricing process is itself disturbed that
a misdirection of production can occur. The “wrong” prices, on the other hand,
which lead to “wrong” dispositions, cannot in turn be explained by mistake.
·
Once we
assume that, even at a single point, the pricing process fails to equilibrate
supply and demand, so that over a more or less long period demand may be
satisfied at prices at which the available supply is inadequate to meet total
demand, then the march of economic events loses its determinateness and a range
of indeterminateness appears, within which movements can originate leading away
from equilibrium. And it is rightly assumed, as we shall see later on,
that it is precisely the behaviour of interest, the price of credit, which
makes possible these disturbances in price formation.
·
One must regard it [credit] rather as a new
determining factor whose appearance causes these deviations and whose effects
must form our starting-point when deducing all those phenomena which can be observed
in cyclical fluctuations. Only when we have succeeded in doing this can we
claim to have explained the phenomena described.
·
...the proposition that, in a barter economy, interest
forms a sufficient regulator for the proportional development of the production
of capital goods and consumption goods, respectively. If it is admitted that,
in the absence of money, interest would effectively prevent any excessive
extension of the production of production goods, by keeping it within the
limits of the available supply of savings, and that an extension of the stock
of capital goods which is based on a voluntary postponement of consumers’
demand into the future can never lead to disproportionate extensions, then it
must also necessarily be admitted that disproportional developments in the
production of capital goods can arise only through the independence of the
supply of free money capital from the accumulation of savings; which in turn
arises from the elasticity of the volume of money.
·
A change in the volume of money, on the other hand,
represents as it were a one-sided change in demand, which is not
counterbalanced by an equivalent change in supply.
·
One instance of these disturbances in the price
mechanism, brought about by monetary influences – and the one which is the most
important from the point of view of Trade Cycle theory – is that putting out of
action of the “interest brake”…
·
For we can
gain a theoretically unexceptionable explanation of complex phenomena only by
first assuming the full activity of the elementary economic interconnections as
shown by the equilibrium theory, and then introducing, consciously and
successively, just those elements which are capable of relaxing these rigid
inter-relationships.
Monetary
Theories of the Trade Cycle
·
….the main reason for the necessity of the monetary
approach to Trade Cycle theory. It arises from the circumstances that the
automatic adjustment of supply and demand can only be disturbed when money is
introduced into the economic system. This adjustment must be considered,
according to the reasoning which is most clearly expressed in Say’s [Law], as
being always present in a state of the natural economy.
·
…the influence of money should be sought in the fact
that when the volume of money is elastic, there may exist a lack of rigidity in
the relationship between saving and the creation of real capital.
·
The only proper starting-point for any explanation
based on equilibrium theory must be the effect of a change in the volume of
money; for this, in itself, constitutes a new state of affairs, entirely
different from that generally treated within the framework of static theory.
·
In
complete contrast to those economic changes conditioned by 'real* forces,
influencing simultaneously total supply and total demand, changes in the volume
of money have, so to speak, a one-sided influence which elicits no reciprocal
adjustment in the economic activity of different individuals. By deflecting a
single factor, without simultaneously eliciting corresponding changes in other
parts of the system, it dissolves its 'closedness', makes a breach in the rigid
reaction mechanism of the system (which rests on the ultimate identity of supply
and demand) and opens a way for tendencies leading away from the equilibrium
position. As a theory of these one-sided influences, the theory of monetary
economy should, therefore, be able to explain the occurrence of phenomena which
would be inconceivable in the barter economy, and notably the disproportional
developments which give rise to crises. A starting-point for such explanations
should be found in the possibility of alterations in the quantity of money
occurring automatically and in the normal course of events, under the present
organization of money and credit, without the need for violent or artificial
action by any external agency.
·
The rate of interest at which, in an
expanding economy, the amount of new money
entering circulation is just sufficient to keep the price-level stable, is
always lower than the rate which would keep the amount of available
loan-capital equal to the amount simultaneously saved by the public, and
thus, despite the stability of the price-level, it makes possible a development
leading away from the equilibrium position.
·
Increases in the volume of
circulation, which in an expanding economy serve to prevent a drop in the price
level, present a typical instance of a change in the monetary factor calculated
to cause a discrepancy between the money and natural rate of interest without
affecting the price-level. These change are consequently neglected, as a rule,
in dealing with phenomena of disproportionality; but they are bound to lead to
a distribution of productive resources between capital-goods and consumption
goods which differs from the equilibrium distribution, just as those changes in
the monetary factor which do manifest themselves in changes in the price-level.
This case is particularly important, because under contemporary currency
systems the automatic adjustment of the value of money, in the form of a flow
of precious metals, will regularly make available new supplies of purchasing
power which will depress the money rate of interest below its natural level.
·
Since a stable price-level has been
regarded as normal hitherto, far too little investigation has been made into
the effects of these changes in the volume of money, which necessarily cause a
development different from that which would be expected on the basis of static
theory, and which lead to the establishment of a structure of production incapable
of perpetuating itself once the change in the monetary factor has ceased to
operate. Economists have overlooked the fact that the changes in the volume of
money, which, in an expanding economy, are necessary to maintain price
stability, lead to a new state of affairs foreign to static analysis, so that
the development which occurs under a stable price level cannot be regarded as
consonant with static laws. Thus the
disturbances described as resulting from changes in the value of money
form only a small part of the much wider category of deviations from the static
course of events brought about by changes in the volume of money — which
may often exist without changes in the value of money, while they may also fail
to accompany changes in value of money when the latter occur.
·
…most of
the objections raised against monetary theories of cyclical fluctuations rest
on the mistaken idea that their significant contribution consists in deducing
changes in the volume of production from the movement of prices en bloc.
·
We have already shown that it is not
even necessary, in order to ascribe the cause of cyclical fluctuations to
monetary changes, to assume that these monetary causes act through changes in
the general price-level.
It is
therefore impossible to maintain that the importance of monetary theories lies
solely in an explanation of price cycles.
·
But general price changes are no essential
feature of a monetary theory of the Trade Cycle; they are not only
unessential, but they would be completely irrelevant if only they were
completely general— that is, if they affected all prices at the same time and
in the same proportion. The point of real interest to Trade Cycle
theory is the existence of certain deviations in individual price
relations occurring because changes in the volume of money appear at certain
individual points; deviations, that is, away from the position which is necessary
to maintain the whole system in equilibrium. Every disturbance of the
equilibrium of prices leads necessarily to shifts in the structure of
production, which must therefore be regarded a consequences of monetary change,
never as additional separate assumptions. The nature of the changes in the
composition of the existing stock of goods, which are effected through such
monetary changes, depends of course on the point at which the money is injected into the economic system.
·
The
assumption of a 'time lag between the successive changes in various prices has
not been spun out of thin air solely for the purposes of Trade Cycle theory; it
is a correction, based on systematic reasoning, of the mistaken conceptions of
older monetary theories. Of course, the expression 'time lag,' borrowed from
Anglo-American writers and denoting a temporary lagging behind of the changes in
the price of some goods relatively to the changes in the price of other goods,
is a very unsuitable expression when the shifts in relative prices are due to
changes in demand which are themselves conditioned by monetary changes. For
such shifts are bound to continue so long as the change in demand persists.
They disappear only with the disappearance of the disturbing monetary factor.
They cease when money ceases to increase or diminish further; not, however,
when the increase or diminution has itself been wiped out. But, whatever
expression we may use to denote these changes in relative prices and the
changes in the structure of production conditioned by them, there can be no
doubt that they are, in turn, conditioned by monetary causes, which alone make
them possible.
·
…it can be
urged that those changes which are constantly taking place in our money
and credit organization cause a certain price,
the rate of interest, to deviate from the equilibrium position, and that
deviations of this kind necessarily lead to such changes in the relative
position of the various branches of production as are bound later to
precipitate the crisis. There is one important point, however, which must be
emphasized against the above-named critics; namely, that it is not only when
the crisis is directly occasioned by a new monetary factor, separate from that
which originally brought about the boom, that it is to be regarded as
conditioned by monetary causes. Once the monetary causes have brought about
that development in the whole economic system which is known as a
boom, sufficient forces have already been set in motion to ensure that, sooner
or later, when the monetary influence has ceased to operate, a crisis must
occur. The 'cause' of the crisis is, then, the disequilibrium of the whole
economy occasioned by monetary changes and maintained through a longer period,
possibly, by a succession of further monetary changes — a disequilibrium the
origin of which can only be explained by monetary disturbances.
·
…the reason for its [the cycle] continuous
recurrence lies in an 'immanent necessity of the monetary and credit
mechanism.'
·
Among the
phenomena which are fundamentally independent of changes in the value of money,
we must include, first of all, the effects of a rate of interest lowered by
monetary influences, which must necessarily lead to the excessive production of
capital goods. Wicksell and Mises both rightly emphasize the decisive
importance of this factor in the explanation of cyclical phenomena, as its
effect will occur even when the increase in circulation is only just sufficient
to prevent a fall in the price level. Besides this, there exist a number of
other phenomena, by virtue of which a money economy (in the sense of an economy
with a variable money supply) differs from a static economy, which for this reason
are important for a true understanding of the course of the Trade Cycle. They
have been partly described already by Mises, but they can only be clearly
observed by taking as the central subject of investigation not changes in
general prices but the divergences of the relation of particular prices as
compared with the price system of static equilibrium.
The
Fundamental Cause of Cyclical Fluctuations
So far
we have not answered, or have only hinted at an answer to the question why,
under the existing organization of the economic system, we constantly find
those deviations of the money rate of
interest from the equilibrium rate which, as we have seen, must be regarded as
the cause of the periodically recurring disproportionalities in the structure
of production. The problem is, then, to discover the gap in the reaction
mechanism of the modern economic system which is responsible for the fact that certain changes of data, so far from being
followed by a prompt readjustment (i.e. the formation of a new equilibrium)
are, actually, the cause of recurrent shifts in economic activity which
subsequently have to be reversed before a new equilibrium can be established.
·
The new
element which we are seeking is, therefore, to be found in the 'elasticity' of the volume of money at the disposal of the economic system. It is
this element whose presence forms the 'necessary and sufficient condition for
the emergence of the Trade Cycle
·
Yet Professor Mises himself—who is
certainly to be regarded as the most respected and consistent exponent of the
monetary theory of the Trade Cycle in Germany — has, in his latest work,
afforded ample justification for this view of his theory by attributing the
periodic recurrence of the Trade Cycle to the general tendency of Central Banks
to depress the money rate of interest below the natural rate
·
By disregarding those divergencies between
the natural and money rate of interest which arise automatically in the course
of economic development, and by emphasizing those caused by an artificial
lowering of the money rate, the Monetary Theory of the Trade Cycle deprives
itself of one of its strongest arguments; namely, the fact that the process which
it describes must always recur under the existing credit organization,
and that it thus represents a tendency inherent in the economic system, and is
in the fullest sense of the word an endogenous theory.
·
It is an apparently unimportant
difference in exposition which leads one to this view that the Monetary Theory
can lay claim to an endogenous position. The situation in which the money rate
of interest is below the natural rate need not, by any means, originate in a deliberate
lowering of the rate of interest by the banks. The same effect can be
obviously produced by an improvement in the expectations of profit or by a
diminution in the rate of saving, which may drive the natural rate (at which
the demand for and the supply of savings are equal) above its previous level;
while the banks refrain from raising their rate of interest to a proportionate
extent, but continue to lend at the previous rate, and thus enable a greater
demand for loans to be satisfied than would be possible by the exclusive use of
the available supply of savings. The decisive significance of the case quoted
is not, in my view, due to the fact that it is probably the commonest in
practice, but to the fact that it must inevitably recur under the
existing credit organization.
·
Altogether, there are three elements
which regulate the volume of circulating media within a country — changes in
the volume of cash, caused by inflows and outflows of gold; changes in the note
circulation of the Central Banks: and last, and in many ways most important,
the often-disputed 'creation' of deposits by other banks. The interrelations of
these are, naturally, complicated.
·
It has already been pointed out
that, in principle, an increase in the volume of cash, occasioned by an
increase in the volume of trade, also implies a lowering of the money rate of
interest — which gives rise to shifts in the structure of production which
seem, though only temporarily, to be advantageous.
·
If in the course of our investigation,
it is possible to prove that the rate of interest charged by the banks to their
borrowers is not promptly adjusted to all changes in the economic data (as it
would be if the volume of money in circulation were constant) •—either because
the supply of bank credits is, within certain limits, fundamentally independent
of changes in the supply of savings, or because the banks have no particular
interest in keeping the supply of bank credit in equilibrium with the supply of
savings and because it is, in any case, impossible for them to do so — then we
shall have proved that, under the existing credit organization, monetary
fluctuations must inevitably occur and must represent an immanent feature of
our economic system — a feature deserving of the closest examination.
·
What
interests us is precisely the question whether the banks are able to satisfy
the increased demands of business men for credits without being obliged
immediately to raise their interest charges —as would be the case if the supply
of savings and the demand for credits were to be in direct contact, without the
agency of the banks (as for example in the hypothetical Savings market' of
theory); or whether it is even possible for the banks to raise their interest
charges immediately the demand for credits increases. Even the bitterest
opponents of this theory of bank credit are forced to admit that there can be
no doubt that, with the upward swing of the Trade Cycle, a certain
expansion of bank credits takes place.'
·
So far, the starting point of our
argument concerning the origin of additional credits has been the assumption
that the banks receive an increased in-flow of cash which they then use as a
basis for new credits on a much larger scale. We must now inquire how banks
behave when an increased demand for credit makes itself felt. Assuming, as is
preferable, that this increased demand was not caused by a lowering of their
own interest rates, this additional demand is always a sign that the natural
rate of interest has risen — that is, that a given amount of money can now find
more profitable employment than hitherto. The reasons for this can be of very
different kinds.
New
inventions or discoveries, the opening up of new markets, or even bad harvests,
the appearance of entrepreneurs of genius who originate 'new combinations'
(Schumpeter), a fall in wage rates due to heavy immigration; and the
destruction of great blocks of capital by a natural catastrophe, or many
others. We have already seen that none of these reasons is in itself sufficient
to account for an excessive increase of investing activity, which
necessarily engenders a subsequent crisis; but that they can lead to this
result only through the increase in the means of credit which they inaugurate.
But how is it possible for the banks to extend credit, as they undoubtedly do,
following an increase in demand, when no additional cash is flowing into their
vaults? There is no reason to assume that the same cause which has led to an
increased demand for credit will also influence another factor, the cash
position of the banks — which as we know is the only factor determining the
extent to which credit can be granted. So long as the banks maintain a constant
proportion between their cash reserves and their deposits it would be impossible
to satisfy the new demand for credit. The fact that in reality deposits always
do expand relatively to cash reserves, in the course of the boom, so that the
liquidity of the banks is always impaired in such periods, does not of course
constitute a sufficient starting point for an argument in which the increase in
credits is regarded as the decisive factor determining the course and
extent of the cyclical movement. We must attempt to understand fully the causes
and nature of this credit expansion and in particular, its limits. The key to
this problem can only be found in the fact that the ratio of reserves to
deposits does not represent a constant magnitude, but, as experience shows, is
itself variable. But we shall achieve a satisfactory solution only by showing that
the reason for this variability in the reserve is not based on the arbitrary
decisions of the bankers, but is itself conditioned by the general economic
situation. Such an examination of the causes determining the size of the
reserve ratio desired by the banks is all the more important since we had no
theoretical warrant for our previous assumption that it always tends to be constant.
·
…assuming
that the bank recognizes that it can satisfy its eventual need for cash only at
correspondingly higher rates, we can see that the greater loss of profit
entailed by keeping the cash reserve intact will, as a rule, lead the bank to a policy which involves diminishing the size of this non-earning
asset. Besides this, we have the consideration that, in the upward phase of the
cycle, the risks of borrowing are less; and therefore a smaller cash reserve
may suffice to provide the same degree of security. But it is above all for
reasons of competition that the bank which first feels the effect of an
increased demand for credits cannot afford to reply by putting up its interest
charges; for it would risk losing its best customers to other banks which had not
yet experienced a similarly increased demand for credits. There can be little
doubt, therefore, that the bank or banks which are the first to feel the
effects of new credit requirements will be forced to satisfy these even at the
cost of reducing their liquidity.
·
But once one bank or group of banks
has started the expansion, then all the other banks receive, as already
described, a flow of cash which at first enables them to expand credit on their
own account without impairing their liquidity. They make use of this
possibility the more readily since they, in turn, soon feel the increased
demand for credit. Once the process of expansion has become general, however,
the banks soon realize that, for the moment at any rate, they can safely modify
their ideas of liquidity. While expansion by a single bank will soon confront
it with a clearinghouse deficit of practically the same magnitude as the
original new credit, a general expansion carried on at about the same rate by
all banks will give rise to clearing-house claims which, although larger,
mainly compensate one another and so induce only a relatively unimportant cash
drain. If a bank does not at first keep pace with the expansion it will, sooner
or later, be induced to do so, since it will continue to receive cash at the
clearing house as long as it does not adjust itself to the new standard of
liquidity.
So long as this process goes on, it is practically impossible for any
single bank, acting alone, to apply the only control by which the demand for
credit can, in the long run, be successfully kept within bounds; that is, an
increase in its interest charges. Concerted action in this direction, which for
competitive reasons is the only action possible, will ensue only when the
increased cash requirements of business compel the banks to protect their cash
balances by checking further credit expansion, or when the Central Bank has
preceded them by raising its discount rate. This, again, will only happen, as a
rule, when the banks have been induced by the growing drain on their cash to
increase their re-discount. Experience shows, moreover, that the relation
between cheque payments and cash payments alters in favour of the latter as the
boom proceeds, so that an increased proportion of the cash is finally withdrawn
from the banks.
This
phenomenon is easily explained in theory by the fact that a low rate of
interest first raises the prices of capital goods and only subsequently those
of consumption goods, so that the first increases occur in the kind of payments
which are effected in large blocks.* It may lead to the consequence that banks
are not only prevented from granting new credits, but even forced to diminish
credits already granted. This fact may well aggravate the crisis; but it is by
no means necessary in order to bring it about. For this it is quite
enough that the banks should cease to extend the volume of credit; and
sooner or later this must happen. Only so long as the volume of circulating
media is increasing can the money rate of interest be kept below the
equilibrium rate; once it has ceased to increase, the money rate must, despite
the increased total volume in circulation, rise again to its natural level and
thus render unprofitable (temporarily, at least) those investments which were
created with the aid of additional credit.
·
By creating additional credits in
response to an increased demand, and thus opening up new possibilities of
improving and extending production, the banks ensure that impulses towards
expansion of the productive apparatus shall not be so immediately and
insuperably balked by a rise of interest rates as they would be if progress
were limited by the slow increase in the flow of savings. But this same policy
stultifies the automatic mechanism of adjustment which keeps the various parts
of the system in equilibrium, and makes possible disproportionate developments
which must, sooner or later, bring about a reaction.
Elasticity
in the credit supply of an economic system, is not only universally demanded
but also — as the result of an organization of the credit system which has
adapted itself to this requirement — an undeniable fact, whose necessity or
advantages are not discussed here. But we must be quite clear on one point. An
economic system with an elastic currency must, in many instances, react
to external influences quite differently from an economy in which
economic forces impinge on goods in their full force — without any
intermediary; and we must a priori, expect any process started by
an outside impulse to run an entirely different course in such an economy from
that described by a theory which only takes into account changes originating on
the side of goods. Once, owing to the disturbing influence of money,
even a single price has been fixed at a different level from that which
it would have formed in a barter economy, a shift in the whole
structure of production is inevitable; and this shift, so long as we
make use of static theory and the methods proper to it, can only be
explained as an exclusive consequence of the peculiar influence
of money. The immediate consequence of an adjustment of the volume of
money to the 'requirements' of industry is the failure of the
'interest brake' to operate as promptly as it would in an economy
operating without credit. This means, however, that new adjustments are
undertaken on a larger scale than can be completed; a boom is thus made
possible, with the inevitably recurring 'crisis.' The determining
cause of the cyclical fluctuation is, therefore, the fact that on account of
the elasticity of the volume of currency media the rate of interest demanded by
the banks is not necessarily always equal to the equilibrium rate, but is, in the short run, determined by considerations of banking liquidity.
·
It must be emphasized first and
foremost that there is no necessary reason why the initiating change, the
original disturbance eliciting a cyclical fluctuation in a stationary economy,
should be of monetary origin. Nor, in practice, is this even generally the
case. The initial change need have no specific character at all, it may be any
one among a thousand different factors which may at any time increase the
profitability of any group of enterprises. For it is not the occurrence of a
change of data' which is significant, but the fact that the economic system,
instead of reacting to this change with an immediate 'adjustment*
(Schumpeter) — i.e. the formation of a new equilibrium — begins a
particular movement of 'boom' which contains, within itself, the seeds of an
inevitable reaction. This phenomenon, as we have seen, should undoubtedly be
ascribed to monetary factors, and in particular to 'additional credits' which
also necessarily determine the extent and duration of the cyclical fluctuation.
Once this point is agreed upon, it naturally becomes quite irrelevant whether
we label this explanation of the Trade Cycle as a monetary theory or not. What
is important is to recognize that it is to monetary causes that we must ascribe
the divergences of the pricing process, during the Trade Cycle, from the course
deduced in static theory.
From the
particular point of view from which we started, our theory must be regarded
most decisively as a monetary one. As to the incorporation of Trade Cycle
theory into the general framework of static equilibrium theory (for the clear
formulation of which we are indebted to Professor A. Lowe, one of the strongest
opponents of monetary Trade Cycle theory), we must maintain, in opposition to
his view, not only that our own theory is undoubtedly a monetary one but that a
theory other than monetary is hardly conceivable. It must be conceded that the
monetary theory as we have presented it — whether one prefers to call it a
monetary theory or not, and whether or not one finds it a sufficient
explanation of the empirically determined fluctuations-has this definite
advantage: it deals with problems which must, in any case, be dealt
with for they are necessarily given when the central apparatus of
economic analysis is applied to the explanation of the existing
organization of exchange. Even if we had never noticed cyclical
fluctuations, even if all the actual fluctuations of history were accepted
as the consequences of natural events, a consequential analysis of the effects
which follow from the peculiar workings of our existing credit organization
would be bound to demonstrate that fluctuations caused by monetary factors are
unavoidable.
·
Whatever further hypothetical causes
are adduced to explain the empirically observed course of the fluctuations,
there can be no doubt (and this is the important and indispensable contribution
of monetary Trade Cycle theory) that the modern economic system cannot be
conceived without fluctuations ascribable to monetary influences; and therefore
any other factors which may be found necessary to explain the empirically
observed phenomena will have to be regarded as causes additional to the
monetary cause. In other words, any non-monetary Trade Cycle theory must
superimpose its system of explanation on that of the monetarily determined
fluctuations; it cannot start simply from the static system as presented by
pure equilibrium theory.
·
The fact, simple and indisputable as
it is, that the Elasticity' of the supply of currency media, resulting from the
existing monetary organization, offers a sufficient reason for the genesis and
recurrence of fluctuations in the whole economy is of the utmost importance —
for it implies that no measure which can be conceived in practice would be able
entirely to suppress these fluctuations.
It
follows particularly from the point of view of the monetary theory of the Trade
Cycle, that it is by no means justifiable to expect the total disappearance of
cyclical fluctuations to accompany a stable price-level — a belief which
Professor Lowe seems to regard as the necessary consequence of the Monetary
Theory of the Trade Cycle. Professor Ropke is undoubtedly right when he
emphasizes the fact that 'even if a stable price level could be successfully
imposed on the capitalist economy the causes making for cyclical fluctuations
would not be removed.
So long
as we make use of bank credit as a means of furthering economic development we
shall have to put up with the resulting trade cycles. They are, in a sense, the
price we pay for a speed of development exceeding that which people would
voluntarily make possible through their savings, and which therefore has to be
extorted from them. And even if it is a mistake — as the recurrence of crises
would demonstrate — to suppose that we can, in this way, overcome all obstacles
standing in the way of progress, it is at least conceivable that the
non-economic factors of progress, such as technical and commercial knowledge,
are thereby benefited in a way which we should be reluctant to forgo.
“Forced Saving” (not a
headline in the book)
There
have recently been increasingly frequent objections to this account of the
effects of an increased volume of currency, and the artificial lowering of
interest rates conditioned by it, on the grounds that it disregards certain
supposedly beneficial effects which are closely connected with this phenomenon.
What the objectors have in mind is the phenomenon of so-called 'forced saving'
which has received great attention in recent literature. This phenomenon, we
are to understand, consists in an increase in capital creation at the cost of
consumption, through the granting of additional credit, without voluntary
action on the part of the individuals who forgo consumption, and without their
deriving any immediate benefit. According to the usual presentation of the
theory of forced saving, this occurs through a fall in the general value of
money, which diminishes the consumers' purchasing power; the volume of goods
thus freed can be used by the producers who obtained additional credits.
We must,
however, raise the same objection ta this theory which we raised against the
usual account of the effects of an artificial lowering of the money rate of
interest, i.e. that, in principle, forced saving takes place whenever the
volume of money is increased, and does not need to manifest itself in changes
in the value of money. The 'depreciation' of money in the hands of the consumer
can be, and frequently will be, only relative, in the sense that those
diminutions in price which would otherwise have occurred are prevented from
occurring. Even this causes a part of the social dividend to be distributed to individuals
who have not acquired legitimate claim to it through previous services, nor
taken them over from others legitimately entitled to them. It is thus taken
away from this part of the community against its will. After what has been said
above, this process needs no further illumination. Nor do we need to adduce further
proof that every grant of additional credit induces 'forced saving
— even
if we have avoided using this rather unfortunate expression in the course of
our argument. There is only one further point — the effect of this artificially
induced capital accumulation — on which a few remarks should be added. It has
often been argued that the forced saving arising from an artificially lowered
interest rate would improve the capital supply of the economy to such an extent
that the natural rate of interest would have to fall finally to the level of
the money rate of interest, and thus a new state of equilibrium would be
created —that is, the crisis could be avoided altogether. This view is closely
connected with the thesis, which we have already rejected, that the level of
the natural rate of interest depends directly upon the whole existing stock of
real capital. Forced saving increases only the existing stock of real capital
goods, but not necessarily the current supply of free capital disposable for
investment
— that portion
of total income which is not consumed but used as a provision for the upkeep
and depreciation of fixed plant. But any addition to the supply of free capital
available for new investment or reinvestment must come from those of the investments
induced by forced savings which already yield a return; a return large enough
to leave over, after providing for supplementary costs connected with the new means
of production, a surplus for depreciation and for interest payments on the capital.
If the capital supply from this source is to lower the natural rate of interest,
it must not, of course, be offset by a diminution elsewhere — resulting from
the decline of other undertakings confronted with the reinforced competition of
those newly supplied with capital. The assumption that an artificial increase
of fixed capital (i.e. one caused by additional credits) tends to diminish the
natural rate of interest in the same way as one effected through voluntary savings
activity presupposes, therefore, that the new capital must be incorporated into
the economic system in such a way that the prices of the products imputed to it
shall cover interest and depreciation. Now a given stock of capital goods is not
a factor which will maintain and renew itself automatically, irrespective of
whether it is in accordance with the current supply of savings or not. The fact
that investments have been undertaken which cannot be 'undone* offers no
guarantee whatever that this is the case. Whether capital can be created beyond
the limits set by voluntary saving depends — and this is just as true for its
renewal as for the creation of new plant — on whether the process of credit creation
continues in a steadily increasing ratio. If the new processes of production are
to be completed, and if those already in existence are to continue in
employment, it is essential that additional credits should be continually injected
at a rate which increases fast enough to keep ahead, by a constant proportion,
of the expanding purchasing power of the consumer. If a new process of roundabout
production can be completed while these conditions still hold good, it can
contribute temporarily to a lowering of the natural rate of interest; but this
provides no final solution of the difficulty.
For,
eventually, a moment must inevitably arrive when the banks are unable any
longer to keep up the rate of inflation required, and at that moment there must
always be some processes of production, newly undertaken and not yet completed,*
which were only ventured because the rate of interest was kept artificially
low. It does not follow, of course, that these processes in particular will be
left unfinished because of the subsequent rise in that rate; on the other hand,
their existence does cause the rate of interest to be higher than it would be
in their absence, when capital would be required only by processes made possible
by voluntary saving without any competing demand arising from processes which
were only enabled to start by 'forced saving.' The capital invested in new and
not yet completed processes of production will thus merely intensify the demand
for further supplies by calling for the capital necessary to complete them — an
effect which will be the more pronounced the greater the ratio of capital invested to capital still
required.
It may therefore quite easily come about that, in order
to complete these newly initiated processes, capital may be diverted from the
maintenance of complete and old-established undertakings, so that new plant is
put into operation and old plant closed down, although the latter would have been
kept up, and the former never put in hand, if it had been a question of
building up the whole capital equipment of the economy from the start.
This does not merely mean that the total return comes
to less than it otherwise would; it also means, primarily, that production is
forced into channels to which it will only keep for as long as the new and spuriously
produced stock of fixed capital can remain in use. The value of capital invested
in processes which can be continued, and, still more, that in processes where
continuance is impracticable, will shrink rapidly in value — this shrinkage being
accompanied by the phenomena of a crisis. Thus on purely technical grounds it
will become uneconomic to maintain them. It should be particularly remarked
that, from the point of view of the fate of individual enterprises, capital
invested in fixed plant, but raised by borrowing, is of precisely the same importance
as working capital, i.e. the loss of value does not merely necessitate writing
down, it generally makes it impossible to carry on at all. The cause of this
development is, evidently, that an unwarranted accumulation of capital has been
taking place; though people may regard it (under the alluring name of * forced
saving') as a thoroughly desirable phenomenon. After what has been said above it
is probably more proper to regard forced saving as the cause of economic
crises than to expect it to restore a balanced structure of production.
------“Forced Saving” end.
·
Here again we have to repeat what
was asserted at the beginning of this book: statistics can never prove or
disprove a theoretical explanation, they can only present problems or offer
fields for theoretical research.
If the
results of our theoretical analysis were to be subjected to statistical
investigation, it is not the connection between changes in the volume of bank
credit and movements in the price level which would have to be explored.
Investigation would have to start on the one hand from alterations in the rate of
increase and decrease in the volume and turnover of bank deposits and, on the other,
from the extent of production in those industries which as a rule expand
excessively as a result of credit injection.* Every increase in the circulating
media brings about the same effect, so long as each stands in the same
proportion to the existing volume; and only an increase in this proportion
makes possible a further increase in investment activity. On the other hand,
every diminution of the rate of increase in itself causes some portion
of existing investment, made possible through credit creation, to become
unprofitable.
It
follows that a curve exhibiting the monetary influences on the course of the cycle
ought to show, not the movements in the total volume of circulating media, but
the alteration in the rate of change of this volume. Every up-turn of this curve
would show that an artificial lowering of the money rate of interest or, if the
curve was already rising, a further lowering of the money rates, was making
possible additional investments for which voluntary savings would not suffice;
and every down-turn would show that current credit-creation was no longer
sufficient to ensure the continuance of all the enterprises which it originally
called into existence. It would be of great interest to correlate this
presentation of the influence causing an excessive production of capital goods
with actual changes in the production of these goods, on the basis of available
data.
·
No less important would be an
investigation into the volume, at any given moment, of those factors which
determine credit expansion, under the other headings of bank balance sheets,
and, in particular, an examination of the relation between the total amount of
earning assets and the current accounts, the relation between these and the
cash-circulation, and so on. Such an investigation, if it were not merely to
exhibit their movements in time but also to analyse the deeper connections
between them, and most especially if it were to clear up the relationship
between interest rates, profits, and the liquidity of the banks, would further
our insight into the factors determining credit expansion as well as our
knowledge of their limits, and thus make it possible to forecast movements in
the factors determining the total development of the economic situation.
Link
to Hayek's "Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle": http://mises.org/daily/3121
Link to Hayek's "Prices and Production": http://mises.org/document/681/
Link to Mises' Human Action: http://mises.org/document/3250 - Chapter XX. Interest, Credit Expansion, and the Trade Cycle deals directly with the ABCT.
Link to Hayek's "Prices and Production": http://mises.org/document/681/
Link to Mises' Human Action: http://mises.org/document/3250 - Chapter XX. Interest, Credit Expansion, and the Trade Cycle deals directly with the ABCT.