Source: Activist Post |
At the end of the 1990s and early 2000s we had the dot-com and telecom bubbles. Not long thereafter we had the housing bubble. To many, these bubbles might be viewed as totally separate and unrelated events that had nothing in common other than being bubbles. However, these (and most other major bubbles during the last hundred years in the U.S. and many other countries) all had two things in common. Firstly, they all popped. Secondly, there was one major player that could always be found in the centre of all these booms and busts; the banking system.
The banking system, with the elastic money
supply it imposes on the market, backed by the support of elected politicians
and the ignorance of voters, ensures the economy finds itself almost continually
in a state of crisis. Domestic- and cross-border crises meetings, ever new
regulations imposed on banks and the finance industry, bail-outs, bail-ins, and
state (partial) takeovers of banks and non-banks, are all evidence of economies
in a situation of more or less crisis. The
larger the degree of socialism (combined with an elastic money supply – a major
tool for central planning distributions and re-distributions of money and
income) the bigger the risk an economy will find itself permanently in
recession.
Banks regularly run into financial problems not by some fault of the free
market or by coincidence, but by political design. Fractional reserve banking is
inherently unsound and can best perhaps be likened to that of a house of
cards or a Ponzi scheme. While sound money is valuable in other uses as well,
today’s fiat money has no intrinsic value whatsoever. We here arrive at a key problem
that is overlooked by the supporters of the money employed today, namely that the value of the bank assets which
are supposed to “back” today’s money are not only themselves dependent on the continued
existence of fiat money, but also on a continual increase in the quantity of them.
To grasp this important flaw of the money employed today consider a mortgage loan secured by the property the borrower buys with the loan granted. Whenever mortgage lending increases, this will help to push house prices higher. The difference between property market prices and the book values of loans increases as a result. Both banks and borrowers benefit as the value of the collateral now more than covers the loan while borrowers’ equity position improves similarly. The more new money that’s lent into existence into the housing market the better the financial position of already existing mortgages will be for both banks and borrowers. Whenever the quantity of money chasing houses outpaces the number of houses for sale, prices are likely to continue to rise. The issuance of mortgage loans serves to increase the former, a key component determining the marginal demand for housing. We can now see how fractional reserve banking can be likened to a house of cards: house prices and the monetary value of the collateral are determined to a large extent by the increase in the issuance of the mortgage loans themselves which are created out of thin air!
To grasp this important flaw of the money employed today consider a mortgage loan secured by the property the borrower buys with the loan granted. Whenever mortgage lending increases, this will help to push house prices higher. The difference between property market prices and the book values of loans increases as a result. Both banks and borrowers benefit as the value of the collateral now more than covers the loan while borrowers’ equity position improves similarly. The more new money that’s lent into existence into the housing market the better the financial position of already existing mortgages will be for both banks and borrowers. Whenever the quantity of money chasing houses outpaces the number of houses for sale, prices are likely to continue to rise. The issuance of mortgage loans serves to increase the former, a key component determining the marginal demand for housing. We can now see how fractional reserve banking can be likened to a house of cards: house prices and the monetary value of the collateral are determined to a large extent by the increase in the issuance of the mortgage loans themselves which are created out of thin air!
Likewise, as continuous successful mortgage lending from a banking point of
view is dependent on ever more money flooding into the property sector and ever-rising property prices, mortgage
lending have the features of a Ponzi scheme. One
difference between the two is that savings (already existing money) are usually
employed in a Ponzi scheme, while newly created money is employed in mortgage
lending. Unless of course the scheme leads to large-scale wasting of resources,
Ponzi schemes, no matter how big, could never create a financial crisis like
mortgage lending can. When
the loan growth ends, or slows down, the marginal demand for housing will
decrease and prices will fall unless offset by other factors (e.g. foreign
buyers bidding prices up). Many house owners will now find themselves
“underwater” as the drop in market values fall below the balance of the
mortgages. Banks’ collateral position takes a hit and delinquencies might increase.
A relevant proportion of borrowers might later default partly or completely on
mortgage payments. Whenever banks then foreclose on a portion of the mortgages
they will, especially on the later loans granted, discover that the market
value of houses foreclosed on are lower than the loans outstanding. It now
becomes evident that the mortgages was backed by little other than the fiat
money that themselves were issued from, and backed by, absolutely nothing. The
house of card crumbles. The 2006/07 to 2008/09 banking crisis is a staggering
example of how fragile mortgage lending can indeed be. A final feature of
mortgage lending worth mentioning is that banks end up with a claim on a real
asset in exchange for money created out of nowhere with no previous sacrifice.
The fragility of the fractional reserve design
manifests itself in two main areas for the banks: 1) only a small fraction of
deposits are kept as reserves, and 2) long term assets (loans) are largely
financed by short term debt (deposits). Any provocation of either one of the
two will swiftly reveal the underlying financial weakness at a bank. The
inherent illiquidity of a bank will become evident once a large enough
proportion of depositors attempt to withdraw their funds as would be the case
during a classic bank run (customers run to the bank to withdraw cash) or during
an electronic bank run (when customers transfer their deposits electronically
to another bank). The duration mismatch between bank assets and liabilities
also presents ongoing challenges in addition to the risk of a bank run. Firstly,
the market value of bank assets fluctuates while its liabilities are largely
fixed and redeemable at par. A fall in the value of assets can therefore wipe
out a bank’s equity. Secondly, a significant portion of the assets are fairly
illiquid and hence cannot be quickly converted to cash should the need arise.
The inherent lack of bank liquidity is not caused by rogue bank management, but is instead a direct
reflection of an accounting entry and how the banking system actually is
designed: when a loan is issued, the bank records on its balance sheet an asset
(the loan, which is typically longer term) and a liability (the deposit, which
the borrower can withdraw at any time). The duration mismatch is therefore
created at the onset.
Combined, these balance sheet weaknesses mean banks are
constantly at the mercy of depositors and lenders. Furthermore, banks are
ever-dependent on market confidence, economic stability, and, ideally, rising
prices which the banks themselves help create through bank credit growth. But, as banks are the creators of the boom
and bust culture which breeds economic instability, it should be obvious why
banks always find themselves at the epicenter of financial crises – all
financial crises originates within the banking sector itself. That’s why all financial crises are in fact banking
crises.
No comments:
Post a Comment